Bank governance and regulation (2024)

Regulations for banks are being rewritten in response to the global financial crisis. The Basel III framework is being adopted, capital requirements are being increased, and safety nets have expanded in scope and size, all with the aim of making banks safer. These financial reforms and re-regulations, however, ignore bank governance – the ownership of banks and the incentives and conflicts that arise between bank owners and managers. But what if the governance structure of banks is intrinsically linked to bank risk? And what if bank governance interacts with regulation to shape bank stability?

This emphasis on using official regulations to induce sound banking while ignoring the role of bank governance is surprising because standard agency theories suggest that ownership structure influences corporate risk-taking (Jensen and Meckling 1976). This gap is also potentially serious from a policy perspective. The same regulations could have different effects on bank risk-taking depending on the comparative power of shareholders within the ownership structure of each bank. Changes in policies toward bank ownership, such as allowing private equity groups to invest in banks or changing limits on ownership concentration, could have very different effects on bank stability depending on other bank regulations.

Yet research on bank risk-taking typically does not incorporate information on each bank’s ownership structure. In an exception, Saunders et al (1990) find that owner-controlled banks exhibit higher risk-taking behaviour than banks controlled by managers with small shareholdings. They do not, however, analyse whether ownership structure and regulations jointly shape bank risk-taking, or whether their results generalise beyond the United States to countries with distinct laws and regulations.

Banks naturally take more risk than is optimal for society because their shareholders are subject to limited liability. As in any limited liability firm, diversified owners have incentives to increase bank risk after collecting funds from bondholders and depositors (Galai and Masulis 1976). However, the ability of bank shareholders to maximise their equity value by increasing risk depends in part on the preferences of the bank’s managers and on the constraints imposed on bank risk-taking by bank regulation and the regulators that enforce such regulation (Buser et al 1981).

The risk-taking incentives of bank managers will depend on the degree to which their interests are linked to those of value-maximising stockholders. Managers with bank-specific human capital skills and private benefits of control tend to advocate less risk-taking than stockholders without those skills and benefits (Jensen and Meckling 1976, Demsetz and Lehn 1985, John et al 2008). From this perspective, banks with an ownership structure that empowers diversified owners take on more risk than banks with owners who play a more subdued governance role. Of course, to the extent that the manager has a large equity stake in the bank or holds stock options, this would enhance his or her risk-taking incentives by enticing them with potentially large rewards for high-return investments. In practice, however, bank managers often do not hold much bank stock, placing them at odds with diversified bank owners in their views on risk-taking.

To complicate matters further, the effectiveness of bank regulation to curtail bank risk-taking will also depend on the incentives of the bank regulators that enforce such regulations. With self-interested bank regulators that have private benefits or concerns (such as reputational concerns from intervening in banks) or can be captured by industry, regulation to constrain bank risk-taking may be muted.

Theory also predicts that regulations influence the risk-taking incentives of diversified owners differently from those of debt holders and non-shareholder managers. For example, deposit insurance intensifies the ability and incentives of stockholders to increase risk (Merton 1977, Keeley 1990). The impetus for greater risk-taking generated by deposit insurance operates on owners, not necessarily on non-shareholder managers. As a second example, consider capital regulations. One goal of capital regulations is to reduce the risk-taking incentives of owners by forcing owners to place more of their personal wealth at risk in the bank (Kim and Santomero 1994). Capital regulations need not reduce the risk-taking incentives of influential owners, however. Specifically, although capital regulations might induce the bank to raise capital, they might not force influential owners to invest more of their wealth in the bank. Furthermore, capital regulations might increase risk-taking. Owners might compensate for the loss of utility from more stringent capital requirements by selecting a riskier investment portfolio (Gale 2010), intensifying conflicts between owners and managers over bank risk-taking. As a final example, many countries attempt to reduce bank risk by restricting banks from engaging in non-lending activities, such as securities and insurance underwriting. As with capital requirements, however, these activity restrictions could reduce the utility of owning a bank, intensifying the risk-taking incentives of owners relative to managers. Thus, the impact of regulations on risk depends on the comparative influence of owners within the governance structure of each bank.

While banking theory suggests that bank regulations affect the risk-taking incentives of owners differently from those of managers, corporate governance theory suggests that ownership structure affects the ability of owners to influence risk. As argued by Shleifer and Vishny (1986), shareholders with larger voting and cash-flow rights have correspondingly greater power and incentives to shape corporate behaviour than smaller owners. From this perspective, ownership structure influences the ability of owners to alter bank risk in response both to standard risk-shifting incentives and to incentives created by official regulations.

Taken together, these theories predict that diversified owners have stronger incentives to increase risk than non-shareholder managers, so banks with powerful, diversified owners tend to be riskier than widely held banks, holding other factors constant. They also predict that bank regulations affect the risk-taking incentives of owners differently from managers, so the actual impact of regulations on risk-taking depends on the comparative power of shareholders relative to managers within each bank’s corporate governance structure.

In a recent paper (Laeven and Levine 2009), we make a first attempt to test how national regulations interact with a bank’s private governance structure to determine its risk-taking behaviour. We find that banks with more powerful owners (as measured by the size of their shareholdings) tend to take greater risks. This supports arguments predicting that equity holders have stronger incentives to increase risk than non-shareholding managers and debt holders, and that owners with substantial cash flows have the power and incentives to induce the bank’s managers to increase risk-taking.

Furthermore, the impact of bank regulations on bank risk depends critically on each bank’s ownership structure such that the relation between regulation and bank risk can change sign depending on ownership structure. For example, the results suggest that deposit insurance is only associated with an increase in risk when the bank has a large equity holder with sufficient power to act on the additional risk-taking incentives created by deposit insurance. The data also suggest that owners seek to compensate for the loss in value of owning a bank from capital regulations by increasing bank risk. Stricter capital regulations are associated with greater risk when the bank has a sufficiently powerful owner, but stricter capital regulations have the opposite effect in widely held banks. Ignoring bank governance leads to incomplete and sometimes erroneous conclusions about the impact of bank regulations on bank risk-taking.

These findings have important policy implications. They question the current approach to bank supervision and regulation that relies on internationally established capital regulations and supervisory practices. Instead, private governance mechanisms exert a powerful influence over bank risking and the same official regulation has different effects on bank risk-taking depending on the bank’s governance structure. Since governance structures differ systematically across countries, bank regulations must be custom-designed and adapted as financial governance systems evolve. Regulations should be geared toward creating sound incentives for owners, managers, and debt holders, not toward harmonising national regulations across economies with very different governance structures.

Naturally, regulations will shape the future of banking. It is not too late for bank regulation to condition on bank governance, and for supervision with limited resources to make the enforcement of regulation a function of a bank’s governance structure. For example, supervisors could allocate a disproportionate amount of their resources to supervising those banks that corporate governance theory would indicate are intrinsically more inclined to take risk, such as owner-controlled banks and/or banks with concentrated ownership. More generally, the risk-taking of banks will depend on the underlying incentives and preferences of the banks managers and owners, including their ownership and wealth concentration in the bank.

Finally, it is important to recognise that the risk-shifting incentives of banks arising from limited liability would be significantly reduced if bank owners would be subject to extended liability – for example, through double liability which holds each shareholder liable to the amount of the par value of the shares held by him, in addition to the amount invested in such shares (Esty 1998). While holding shareholders liable for a portion of the bank’s debts after insolvency would significantly increase the cost of capital and therefore reduce the lending capacity of banks with potentially negative ramifications for growth, it would create safer banks and therefore should not easily be discarded as a policy option to enhance financial stability.

Disclaimer: While the author of this chapter is a staff member of the International Monetary Fund, the views expressed herein are those of the author and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.

References

Buser, S, A Chen, and E Kane (1981) “Federal Deposit Insurance, Regulatory Policy, and Optimal Bank Capital,” Journal of Finance 36, 51-60.

Demsetz, H and K Lehn (1985) “The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences,” Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155-1177.

Esty, B (1998) “The Impact of Contingent Liability on Commercial Bank Risk-taking,” Journal of Financial Economics 47, 189-218.

Galai, D and R Masulis (1976) “The Option Pricing Model and the Risk Factor of Stock,” Journal of Financial Economics 3, 53-81.

Gale, D (2010) “Capital Regulation and Risk Sharing,” International Journal of Central Banking 23, 187-204.

Jensen, M and W Meckling (1976) “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.

John, K, L Litov and B Yeung (2008) “Corporate Governance and Managerial Risk-taking: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Finance 63, 1679-1728.

Keeley, M (1990) “Deposit Insurance, Risk, and Market Power in Banking,” American Economic Review 80, 1183-1200.

Kim, D and A Santomero (1994) “Risk in Banking and Capital Regulation,” Journal of Finance 43, 1219-1233.

Laeven, L and R Levine (2009) “Bank Governance, Regulation, and Risk-Taking,” Journal of Financial Economics 93, 259-275.

Merton, R (1977) “An Analytic Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantees: An Application of Modern Option Pricing Theory,” Journal of Banking and Finance 1, 3-11.

Saunders, A, E Strock, and NG Travlos (1990) “Ownership Structure, Deregulation, and Bank Risk-taking, Journal of Finance 45, 643-654.

Shleifer, A and R Vishny (1986) “Large Shareholders and Corporate Control,” Journal of Political Economy 94, 461-488.

I am an expert in the field of banking and financial regulations, with a deep understanding of the dynamics between bank governance, ownership structures, and risk-taking behavior. My expertise is grounded in both theoretical frameworks and empirical evidence, allowing me to provide valuable insights into the complex interplay of factors shaping the stability and risk profile of banks.

In the article, the focus is on the evolving landscape of regulations for banks, particularly in response to the global financial crisis. The adoption of the Basel III framework, increased capital requirements, and expanded safety nets are highlighted as measures aimed at enhancing the safety of banks. However, the article argues that these reforms often overlook the crucial aspect of bank governance—the ownership structure and the incentives and conflicts arising from the relationships between owners and managers.

The article draws on established agency theories, such as the work of Jensen and Meckling (1976), to emphasize that ownership structure influences corporate risk-taking. It questions the surprising gap in the consideration of bank governance in the context of financial reforms and regulations. The potential impact of changes in policies toward bank ownership, such as allowing private equity groups to invest or altering ownership concentration limits, is suggested to vary depending on the comparative power of shareholders within each bank's ownership structure.

The discussion delves into the inherent risk-taking tendencies of banks, driven by limited liability, and highlights the role of bank managers in influencing risk-taking incentives. The article argues that the risk-taking behavior of bank managers depends on the alignment of their interests with value-maximizing stockholders. It suggests that banks with ownership structures empowering diversified owners might take on more risk than those with more subdued governance roles.

The complexity is further accentuated by the role of bank regulations in shaping risk-taking incentives. Deposit insurance, capital regulations, and restrictions on non-lending activities are explored as examples, with the article positing that the impact of regulations varies depending on the comparative influence of owners within the governance structure of each bank.

Theories from both banking and corporate governance perspectives are integrated to predict that diversified owners have stronger incentives to increase risk than non-shareholder managers. Consequently, banks with powerful, diversified owners are posited to be riskier than widely held banks, holding other factors constant. The article concludes with findings from a study by Laeven and Levine (2009), suggesting that the risk-taking behavior of banks is influenced by the interaction between national regulations and a bank's private governance structure.

In terms of policy implications, the article calls for a reevaluation of the current approach to bank supervision and regulation. It argues that regulations should be custom-designed, considering the diversity in financial governance systems across countries. The importance of incorporating bank governance into the regulatory framework is underscored, suggesting that regulations should be tailored to create sound incentives for owners, managers, and debt holders, rather than pursuing a one-size-fits-all approach.

In summary, my expertise allows me to critically analyze and synthesize the information presented in the article, offering a comprehensive understanding of the intricate relationships between bank governance, ownership structures, and risk-taking behavior in the context of evolving financial regulations.

Bank governance and regulation (2024)

References

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Nathanael Baumbach

Last Updated:

Views: 6611

Rating: 4.4 / 5 (75 voted)

Reviews: 82% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Nathanael Baumbach

Birthday: 1998-12-02

Address: Apt. 829 751 Glover View, West Orlando, IN 22436

Phone: +901025288581

Job: Internal IT Coordinator

Hobby: Gunsmithing, Motor sports, Flying, Skiing, Hooping, Lego building, Ice skating

Introduction: My name is Nathanael Baumbach, I am a fantastic, nice, victorious, brave, healthy, cute, glorious person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.